Necessarily, the first wave of posts offered brief overviews of the elements contained here, and probably gave short shrift to some key ideas. Thus, before moving on to more specific and no less important aspects of baseball's economic explanatory power, I just wanted to flesh out what I consider to be key ideas in economic affairs that we haven't adequately addressed. And here we see Uncertainty and Complex and Perpetually Novel Outcomes come together.
The notion that uncertainty plays a huge role in baseball and the economy (we've analogized this further to dark energy in the universe) is pretty straightforward, and it should be said that we don't really mean uncertainty in the basic sense that no one knows what will happen in the future. That's pretty obvious and not very insightful. (Again, though, I'm consistently surprised by economic writings that attempt to move, with little success, from description to prediction.)
We mean uncertainty in the sense that because so many things go into determining the outcome of one pitch or one play in baseball, our predictive power is limited no matter the statistical tools we have at our disposal. A new National Bureau of Economic Research working paper puts this succinctly: "Behavioral outcomes are influenced by hundreds of variables and a near-infinity of circumstances, happenstances, and coincidences." (Via Odd Numbers.) Because, at bottom, both baseball and economic activity involve human behavior, and because humans are (gloriously) imperfect, there is an endless array of things that will affect an outcome. The relatively new field of "neuroeconomics" takes this even a step further than behavioral economics.
Some readers might claim to find here somewhat of an inconsistency: we list Moneyball, after all, as one of our top book choices and isn't that all about greater statistical rigor in player evaluation? Surely we're not casting our lot with Joe Morgan and his anti-Moneyball crusade?
When I critique the utility (pun intended) of statistical models in economics, I am saying that because of the nearly infinite variety of factors that go into determining one individual decision let alone the course of a $13-trillion economy of 300 million people connected to the rest of the world, how can we hope to predict or manage anything? The approach of Moneyball, often distorted to on-base percentage and much-maligned as purely numerical, revolves around going beyond the traditional statistics used to measure player performance (like batting average) and trying to get a more complete picture of what players do that adds value to a team's effort. Simply sizing up a player's abilities (five tools, etc) or looking at batting average were seen to be insufficient. This won't be news to many readers.
But I would bet that Billy Beane and Bill James don't pretend that they can predict or micro-manage the on-field performance of teams and players. They try to raise the probability of certain outcomes and, ultimately, victory, but they know there are plenty of things (dark energy) out of their control. In this sense, all the noise in the financial press over the last two years about the Federal Reserve "engineering a soft landing" for the U.S. economy and the potential impact of the economic policies of the next president likely overstates things.
As an example, let's look at developments over the long-term, and this is where we see uncertainty working on a much larger scale of complex and perpetually novel outcomes. Let's take the entire course of a 162-game baseball season, and the American economy in the twentieth-century. (Disproportionate time scales, perhaps, but a useful way to think about it--you'll see.)
If you reran, as it were, an entire baseball season, it is highly unlikely that you would get the same result as before. The events as they actually turned out were only one possible pathway, not the only possible outcome. Anyone who has played Strat-O-Matic or Statis-Pro can tell you this and won't be particularly surprised by this observation. The developments during the 2008 season are not deterministic: the bounce of one batted ball, a close call at home, a quarter-inch difference in a pitch, a slight change in wind conditions. Any of these could alter a discrete outcome--compounded over 162 games, they could change the character of everything. We often here this expressed during a player's chase or .400. A few years ago wasn't it the case that with something like 16 more hits Barry Bonds would have hit .400? Put aside the steroids accusations and all the walks: sixteen more hits could easily have been attained with a few of the changes just mentioned--a different bounce, a fielder's position, etc.
Baseball is not Calvinistic: there is no predestination. Economic change, too, is not Calvinistic. If you reran the economic history of the twentieth century, nothing guarantees an exact replay of what happened in real life. Sure, we probably still would have ended up with mass production of automobiles, cell phones, and the Internet. But the dynamics of everything would likely be different. Detroit was not the foreordained geographic center of the auto industry. Other states and other countries were vying for that as well.
Long-term economic change is often illustrated in economics textbooks by the Production Possibility Frontier, a curve that expands outward as outputs grow. This is a convenient way to depict aggregate economic growth, but doesn't really capture the developmental intricacies of how economic growth feels. Obviously, the point is to represent long-term change in an abstract manner free of potentially-distorting details. But that's like saying at the beginning of a baseball season: some teams will lose, some will win, there will be hits and strikeouts, and at the end there will be one champion. Well, yes that is what happens, but it doesn't really tell us anything about how. Here, in one sense, is an illustration of this. Look at the variety of developmental pathways and niches. Uncertainty and Complex and Perpetually Novel Outcomes are functions of each other.
OK, does this amount to anything more than an observation that contingency plays a large role in baseball and economics? The real payoff is in the implications. We should be careful about applying past lessons to future problems. I would be the first to say let's learn from history, but there's a difference between appealing directly to a past situation and looking instead at the general contours of what has gone before. In this sense, the contemporary debates about whether "Obamanomics" will be like "Clintonomics" or what JFK's tax cuts say about John McCain's economic policies really don't amount to anything meaningful.
We should be more appreciative, in the Popperian sense, of our ignorance: it opens up many more opportunities than a deterministic approach. This is one of the great lessons, for me at least, of David Halberstam's baseball history books: I am consistently surprised in reading them at the unexpected developments, the twists and turns that determined a crucial game or series in 1949 or 1964.
In the next set of posts, we'll begin to take on more specific aspects of baseball and the economy, including entrepreneurship, specialization, long-term dependency effects, and the element of time.
2 comments:
Your reference to Karl Popper's acceptance of "ignorance" is very humbling--and true. However, he did seek to find some pattern, some long-term historical truth.
In "The Open Society" he deplored the devotion of scholars to the history of power politics, wars, heroes, and great events--without any connecting thread to provide meaning. While he says that no meaning can be discerned nor is there any universal history of mankind, he does observe that any such synthesis "would have to be a history of all human hopes, struggles, and sufferings. . . The history of freedom is that we are ourselves responsible for it, in the same sense that we are responsible for what we make of our lives. . . The life of the forgotten, of the unknown individual man; his sorrows and his joys, his suffering and his death, that is the real content of huuman experinece down the ages. . .But such a history does not and cannot exist; and all the history which exists, our history of the Great and Powerful, is at best a shallow comedy."
My analysis of historical progress for the common men and women of the world also finds that great men and great events have more often than not been comedic and harmful. But the progress that occurred (despite the fumbling and butchery) rests precisely on those "human hopes, struggles and sufferings down the ages" that Popper celebrates.Through the ages, many unknown individuals assumed responsibility and helped to achieve freedom, human rights, and an open society. These common people "gave history meaning" by bequeathing to us the legacy of free institutions that they so persistently pursued.
I have traced that history of determined effort in "Common Genius," a 3,000 year historical survey: Progress was originated in those rare locales where free people demonstrated that with some degree of security, and unburdened by oppressive forces, they could and would carve out giant steps forward for all mankind. "The Radzewicz Rule" (you can google it) reduces this lesson of history to an algebraic formula, and reflects Milton Friedman's assertion that "The great advances of civilization. . . were the product of individual genius, of strongly held minority views, of a social climate permitting variety and diversity. Government can never duplicate the variety and diversity of human action."
The extraordinary and varied efforts of millions of free people, each pushing his own particular brand of genius, created progress--but only when allowed the economic freedom to act, to conduct their affairs unhindered from the top, and to keep the fruits of their toil. The resulting avenues of progress were always unpredictable at any one point in time, but the fact that progress would occur from such free human actions, was, and continues to be, totally predictable.
Now baseball is a perfect metaphor for this rule of history. Recall that the freedom to progress was rarely given to mankind--most people lived under rigid autocracies for millennias. They never had a chance to exercize their genius, or keep the products of their work. They were the bench-warmers, slaving away for their mssters, their minds and hands truly invisible, shackled, and unmotivated. But for a society, or a baseball team to win, all the players must produce results. They must be allowed to swing the bat! Unfortunately, the people under Oriental despots and Middle eastern sultanates were never allowed to even get to the plate! Even in much of Europe, the people never had a chance--the miracle of Western civilization emerged from just a few laboratories of history, and it relied primarily on the economic freedom of the individual.
Economists can't readily identify the finite causes of advances because the causes were simply the choices made and efforts put forth by millions of very common and unpredictable human beings. And that is why every new governmental top-down mandate slows down progress by reducing the average Joe's ability to act.
It has been well said that economists, like accountants, arrive on the battle field after the war is over. They count the bodies and examine the fallen weapons, they look for tell-tale signs, they estimate the sorrows and sufferings of the combatants, and from that try and figure out what happened. Then, based on such guestimates, they try and predict the future! But, they never recognize that a chance event, a brave deed, a reckless gamble, or a single human action could have entirely altered the outcome.
Nice to know about things.........
Post a Comment